|
|
Islamic Banking
by Mohamed Ariff, University of Malaya,
taken from Asian-Pacific Economic Literature, Vol. 2, No. 2 (September 1988), pp. 46-62
Islamic banking is a new phenomenon that has taken many observers by
surprise. A significant proportion of the banking system has been islamized
in both Iran and Pakistan. In addition, there are some thirty Islamic banks
in operation in
other parts of the globe, including the Jeddah-based Islamic Development
Bank (IDB) but excluding numerous non-bank Islamic financial institutions
(see Appendix). What is more, the speed with which Islamic banks have
sprung up and the rate at which they have progressed make it worth-while to
study them systematically. An attempt is made in this paper (a) to survey the
growing literature on Islamic banking, in particular (b) to trace the growth
and development of Islamic banking, and (c) to highlight its salient
characteristics.
Contents
The first modern experiment with Islamic banking was undertaken in Egypt
under cover, without projecting an Islamic image, for fear of being seen as a
manifestation of Islamic fundamentalism which was anathema to the
political regime. The pioneering effort, led by Ahmad El Najjar, took the form
of a savings bank based on profit-sharing in the Egyptian town of Mit Ghamr
in l963. This experiment lasted until l967 (Ready l98l), by which time there
were nine such banks in the country. These banks, which neither charged
nor paid interest, invested mostly by engaging in trade and industry,
directly or in partnership with others, and shared the profits with their
depositors (Siddiqi l988). Thus, they functioned essentially as saving-
investment institutions rather than as commercial banks. The Nasir Social
Bank, established in Egypt in l97l, was declared an interest-free commercial
bank, although its charter made no reference to Islam or Shariah (Islamic
law).
The IDB was established in l974 by the Organization of Islamic Countries
(OIC), but it was primarily an inter-governmental bank aimed at providing
funds for development projects in member countries. The IDB provides fee-
based financial services and profit-sharing financial assistance to member
countries. The IDB operations are free of interest and are explicitly based on
Shariah Principles
In the seventies, changes took place in the political climate of many Muslim
countries so that there was no longer any strong need to establish Islamic
financial institutions under cover. A number of Islamic banks, both in letter
and spirit, came into existence in the Middle East, e.g., the Dubai Islamic Bank
(l975), the Faisal Islamic Bank of Sudan (l977), the Faisal Islamic Bank of
Egypt (l977), and the Bahrain Islamic Bank (l979), to mention a few.
The Asia-Pacific region was not oblivious to the winds of change. The
Philippine Amanah Bank (PAB) was established in l973 by Presidential
Decree as a specialized banking institution without reference to its Islamic
character in the bank's charter. The establishment of the PAB was a
response by the Philippines Government to the Muslim rebellion in the
south, designed to serve the special banking needs of the Muslim community.
However, the primary task of the PAB was to assist rehabilitation and
reconstruction in Mindanao, Sulu and Palawan in the south (Mastura l988).
The PAB has eight branches located in the major cities of the southern
Muslim provinces, including one in Makati (Metro Manila), in addition to the
head office located at Zamboanga City in Mindanao. The PAB, however, is not
strictly an Islamic bank, since interest-based operations continue to coexist
with the Islamic modes of financing. It is indeed fascinating to observe that
the PAB operates two 'windows' for deposit transactions, i.e., conventional
and Islamic. Nevertheless, efforts are underway to convert the PAB into a
full-fledged Islamic bank (Mastura l988).
Islamic banking made its debut in Malaysia in l983, but not without
antecedents. The first Islamic financial institution in Malaysia was the
Muslim Pilgrims Savings Corporation set up in l963 to help people save for
performing hajj (pilgrimage to Mecca and Medina). In l969, this body
evolved into the Pilgrims Management and Fund Board or the Tabung Haji as
it is now popularly known. The Tabung Haji has been acting as a finance
company that invests the savings of would-be pilgrims in accordance with
Shariah, but its role is rather limited, as it is a non-bank financial institution. The success of the Tabung Haji, however, provided the main impetus for
establishing Bank Islam Malaysia Berhad (BIMB) which represents a full-
fledged Islamic commercial bank in Malaysia. The Tabung Haji also contributed l2.5 per cent of BIMB's initial capital of M$80 million. BIMB has a
complement of fourteen branches in several parts of the country. Plans are
afoot to open six new branches a year so that by l990 the branch network of
BIMB will total thirty-three (Man l988).
Reference should also be made to some Islamic financial institutions
established in countries where Muslims are a minority. There was a proliferation of interest-free savings and loan societies in India during the seventies (Siddiqi l988). The Islamic Banking System (now called Islamic Finance
House), established in Luxembourg in l978, represents the first attempt at
Islamic banking in the Western world. There is also an Islamic Bank
International of Denmark, in Copenhagen, and the Islamic Investment
Company has been set up in Melbourne, Australia.
Rationale
The essential feature of Islamic banking is that it is interest-free. Although
it is often claimed that there is more to Islamic banking, such as contributions towards a more equitable distribution of income and wealth, and
increased equity participation in the economy (Chapra l982), it nevertheless
derives its specific rationale from the fact that there is no place for the
institution of interest in the Islamic order.
Islam prohibits Muslims from taking or giving interest (riba) regardless of
the purpose for which such loans are made and regardless of the rates at
which interest is charged. To be sure, there have been attempts to
distinguish between usury and interest and between loans for consumption
and for production. It has also been argued that riba refers to usury
practiced by petty money-lenders and not to interest charged by modern
banks and that no riba is involved when interest is imposed on productive
loans, but these arguments have not won acceptance. Apart from a few
dissenting opinions, he general consensus among Muslim scholars clearly is
that there is no difference between riba and interest. In what follows, these
two terms are used interchangeably.
The prohibition of riba is mentioned in four different revelations in the
Qur'an.1 The first revelation emphasizes that interest deprives wealth of
God's blessings. The second revelation condemns it, placing interest in
juxtaposition with wrongful appropriation of property belonging to others.
The third revelation enjoins Muslims to stay clear of interest for the sake of
their own welfare. The fourth revelation establishes a clear distinction
between interest and trade, urging Muslims to take only the principal sum
and to forgo even this sum if the borrower is unable to repay. It is further
declared in the Qur'an that those who disregard the prohibition of interest
are at war with God and His Prophet. The prohibition of interest is also cited
in no uncertain terms in the Hadith (sayings of the Prophet). The Prophet
condemned not only those who take interest but also those who give interest
and those who record or witness the transaction, saying that they are all
alike in guilt.2
It may be mentioned in passing that similar prohibitions are to be found in
the pre-Qur'anic scriptures, although the 'People of the Book', as the Qur'an
refers to them, had chosen to rationalize them. It is amazing that Islam has
successfully warded off various subsequent rationalization attempts aimed at legitimizing the institution of interest.
Some scholars have put forward economic reasons to explain why interest is
banned in Islam. It has been argued, for instance, that interest, being a pre-
determined cost of production, tends to prevent full employment (Khan l968;
Ahmad n.d.; Mannan l970). In the same vein, it has been contended that
international monetary crises are largely due to the institution of interest
(Khan, n.d), and that trade cycles are in no small measure attributable to the
phenomenon of interest (Ahmad l952; Su'ud n.d.). None of these studies,
however, has really succeeded in establishing a causal link between interest,
on the one hand, and employment and trade cycles, on the other. Others,
anxious to vindicate the Islamic position on interest, have argued that
interest is not very effective as a monetary policy instrument even in
capitalist economies and have questioned the efficacy of the rate of interest
as a determinant of saving and investment (Ariff l982).
A common thread running through all these discussions is the exploitative
character of the institution of interest, although some have pointed out that
profit (which is lawful in Islam) can also be exploitative. One response to this is that one must distinguish between profit and profiteering, and Islam has
prohibited the latter as well.
Some writings have alluded to the 'unearned income' aspect of interest payments as a possible explanation for the Islamic doctrine. The objection that
rent on property is considered halal (lawful) is then answered by rejecting
the analogy between rent on property and interest on loans, since the
benefit to the tenant is certain, while the productivity of the borrowed
capital is uncertain. Besides, property rented out is subject to physical wear and tear, while money lent out is not. The question of erosion in the value of money and hence the need for indexation is an interesting one. But the
Islamic jurists have ruled out compensation for erosion in the value of
money, or, according to Hadith, a fungible good must be returned by its like
(mithl): 'gold for gold, silver for silver, wheat for wheat, barley for barley, dates for dates, salt for salt, like for like, equal for equal, and hand to hand ...'.3
The bottom line is that Muslims need no 'proofs' before they reject the
institution of interest: no human explanation for a divine injunction is
necessary for them to accept a dictum, as they recognize the limits to human
reasoning. No human mind can fathom a divine order; therefore it is a
matter of faith (iman).
The Islamic ban on interest does not mean that capital is costless in an
Islamic system. Islam recognizes capital as a factor of production but it does
not allow the factor to make a prior or pre-determined claim on the
productive surplus in the form of interest. This obviously poses the question
as to what will then replace the interest rate mechanism in an Islamic
framework. There have been suggestions that profit-sharing can be a viable
alternative (Kahf l982a and l982b). In Islam, the owner of capital can
legitimately share the profits made by the entrepreneur. What makes profit-
sharing permissible in Islam, while interest is not, is that in the case of the former it is only the profit-sharing ratio, not the rate of return itself that is predetermined.
It has been argued that profit-sharing can help allocate resources
efficiently, as the profit-sharing ratio can be influenced by market forces so that capital will flow into those sectors which offer the highest profit-
sharing ratio to the investor, other things being equal. One dissenting view
is that the substitution of profit-sharing for interest as a resource allocating mechanism is crude and imperfect and that the institution of interest should therefore be retained as a necessary evil (Naqvi l982). However, mainstream
Islamic thinking on this subject clearly points to the need to replace interest with something else, although there is no clear consensus on what form the
alternative to the interest rate mechanism should take. The issue is not
resolved and the search for an alternative continues, but it has not detracted from efforts to experiment with Islamic banking without interest.
As mentioned earlier, Islam does not deny that capital, as a factor of
production, deserves to be rewarded. Islam allows the owners of capital a
share in a surplus which is uncertain. To put it differently, investors in the Islamic order have no right to demand a fixed rate of return. No one is
entitled to any addition to the principal sum if he does not share in the risks involved. The owner of capital (rabbul-mal) may 'invest' by allowing an
entrepreneur with ideas and expertise to use the capital for productive
purposes and he may share the profits, if any, with the entrepreneur-
borrower (mudarib); losses, if any, however, will be borne wholly by the
rabbul-mal. This mode of financing, termed mudaraba in the Islamic
literature, was in practice even in the pre-Qur'anic days and, according to
jurists, it was approved by the Prophet.
Another legitimate mode of financing recognized in Islam is one based on
equity participation (musharaka) in which the partners use their capital
jointly to generate a surplus. Profits or losses will be shared between the
partners according to some agreed formula depending on the equity ratio.
Mudaraba and musharaka constitute, at least in principle if not in practice,
the twin pillars of Islamic banking. The musharaka principle is invoked in
the equity structure of Islamic banks and is similar to the modern concepts
of partnership and joint stock ownership. In so far as the depositors are
concerned, an Islamic bank acts as a mudarib which manages the funds of
the depositors to generate profits subject to the rules of mudaraba as outlined above. The bank may in turn use the depositors' funds on a mudaraba basis in
addition to other lawful modes of financing. In other words, the bank
operates a two-tier mudaraba system in which it acts both as the mudarib on
the saving side of the equation and as the rabbul-mal on the investment
portfolio side. The bank may also enter into musharaka contracts with the
users of the funds, sharing profits and losses, as mentioned above.
At the deposit end of the scale, Islamic banks normally operate three broad
categories of account, mainly current, savings, and investment accounts. The current account, as in the case of conventional banks, gives no return to the depositors. It is essentially a safe-keeping (al-wadiah) arrangement between
the depositors and the bank, which allows the depositors to withdraw their
money at any time and permits the bank to use the depositors' money. As in
the case of conventional banks, cheque books are issued to the current account deposit holders and the Islamic banks provide the broad range of
payment facilities - clearing mechanisms, bank drafts, bills of exchange,
travellers cheques, etc. (but not yet, it seems, credit cards or bank cards).
More often than not, no service charges are made by the banks in this
regard.
The savings account is also operated on an al-wadiah basis, but the bank may
at its absolute discretion pay the depositors a positive return periodically, depending on its own profitability. Such payment is considered lawful in
Islam since it is not a condition for lending by the depositors to the bank, nor is it pre-determined. The savings account holders are issued with savings
books and are allowed to withdraw their money as and when they please.
The investment account is based on the mudaraba principle, and the deposits
are term deposits which cannot be withdrawn before maturity. The profit-
sharing ratio varies from bank to bank and from time to time depending on
supply and demand conditions.4 In theory, the rate of return could be
positive or negative, but in practice the returns have always been positive
and quite comparable to rates conventional banks offer on their term
deposits.5
At the investment portfolio end of the scale, Islamic banks employ a variety
of instruments. The mudaraba and musharaka modes, referred to earlier, are
supposedly the main conduits for the outflow of funds from the banks. In
practice, however, Islamic banks have shown a strong preference for other
modes which are less risky. The most commonly used mode of financing
seems to be the 'mark-up' device which is termed murabaha. In a murabaha
transaction, the bank finances the purchase of a good or asset by buying it
on behalf of its client and adding a mark-up before re-selling it to the client on a 'cost-plus' basis. It may appear at first glance that the mark-up is just another term for interest as charged by conventional banks, interest thus
being admitted through the back door. What makes the murabaha
transaction Islamically legitimate is that the bank first acquires the asset
and in the process it assumes certain risks between purchase and resale. The
bank takes responsibility for the good before it is safely delivered to the
client. The services rendered by the Islamic bank are therefore regarded as
quite different from those of a conventional bank which simply lends money
to the client to buy the good.
Islamic banks have also been resorting to purchase and resale of properties
on a deferred payment basis, which is termed bai' muajjal. It is considered
lawful in fiqh (jurisprudence) to charge a higher price for a good if
payments are to be made at a later date. According to fiqh, this does not
amount to charging interest, since it is not a lending transaction but a
trading one.
Leasing or ijara is also frequently practised by Islamic banks. Under this
mode, the banks would buy the equipment or machinery and lease it out to
their clients who may opt to buy the items eventually, in which case the
monthly payments will consist of two components, i.e., rental for the use of
the equipment and instalment towards the purchase price.
Reference must also be made to pre-paid purchase of goods, which is termed
bai'salam, as a means used by Islamic banks to finance production. Here the
price is paid at the time of the contract but the delivery would take place at a future date. This mode enables an entrepreneur to sell his output to the bank at a price determined in advance. Islamic banks, in keeping with modern
times, have extended this facility to manufactures as well.
It is clear from the above sketch that Islamic banking goes beyond the pure
financing activities of conventional banks. Islamic banks engage in equity
financing and trade financing. By its very nature, Islamic banking is a risky
business compared with conventional banking, for risk-sharing forms the
very basis of all Islamic financial transactions. To minimize risks, however,
Islamic banks have taken pains to distribute the eggs over many baskets and
have established reserve funds out of past profits which they can fall back
on in the event of any major loss.
It is not possible to cover in this survey all the publications which have
appeared on Islamic banking. There are numerous publications in Arabic
and Urdu which have made significant contributions to the theoretical discussion. A brief description of these in English can be found in the Appendix
to Siddiqi's book on Banking without Interest (Siddiqi l983a).
The early contributions on the subject of Islamic banking were somewhat
casual in the sense that only passing references were made to it in the
discussion of wider issues relating to the Islamic economic system as a whole. In other words, the early writers had been simply thinking aloud rather
than presenting well-thought-out ideas. Thus, for example, the book by
Qureshi on Islam and the Theory of Interest (Qureshi l946) looked upon
banking as a social service that should be sponsored by the government like
public health and education. Qureshi took this point of view since the bank
could neither pay any interest to account holders nor charge any interest on
loans advanced. Qureshi also spoke of partnerships between banks and
businessmen as a possible alternative, sharing losses if any. No mention was
made of profit-sharing.
Ahmad, in Chapter VII of his book Economics of Islam (Ahmad l952),
envisaged the establishment of Islamic banks on the basis of a joint stock
company with limited liability. In his scheme, in addition to current
accounts, on which no dividend or interest should be paid, there was an
account in which people could deposit their capital on the basis of
partnership, with shareholders receiving higher dividends than the account
holders from the profits made. Like Qureshi, above, Ahmad also spoke of
possible partnership arrangements with the businessmen who seek capital
from the banks. However, the partnership principle was left undefined, nor
was it clear who would bear the loss if any. It was suggested that banks
should cash bills of trade without charging interest, using the current
account funds.
The principle of mudaraba based on Shariah was invoked systematically by
Uzair (l955). His principal contribution lay in suggesting mudaraba as the
main premise for 'interestless banking'. However, his argument that the
bank should not make any capital investment with its own deposits rendered
his analysis somewhat impractical.
Al-Arabi (l966) envisaged a banking system with mudaraba as the main
pivot. He was actually advancing the idea of a two-tier mudaraba which
would enable the bank to mobilize savings on a mudaraba basis, allocating
the funds so mobilized also on a mudaraba basis. In other words the bank
would act as a mudarib in so far as the depositors were concerned, while the
'borrowers' would act as mudaribs in so far as the bank was concerned. In his
scheme, the bank could advance not only the capital procured through
deposits but also the capital of its own shareholders. It is also of interest to note that his position with regard to the distribution of profits and the
responsibility for losses was strictly in accordance with the Shariah.6
Irshad (l964) also spoke of mudaraba as the basis of Islamic banking, but his
concept of mudaraba was quite different from the traditional one in that he
thought of capital and labour (including entrepreneurship) as having equal
shares in output, thus sharing the losses and profits equally. This actually
means that the owner of capital and the entrepreneur have a fifty-fifty
share in the profit or loss as the case may be, which runs counter to the
Shariah position. Irshad envisaged two kinds of deposit accounts. The first
sounded like current deposits in the sense that it would be payable on
demand, but the money kept in this deposit would be used for social welfare
projects, as the depositors would get zero return. The second one amounted to
term deposits which would entitle the depositors to a share in the profits at
the end of the year proportionately to the size and duration of the deposits.
He recommended the setting up of a Reserve Fund which would absorb all
losses so that no depositor would have to bear any loss. According to Irshad,
all losses would be either recovered from the Reserve Fund or borne by the
shareholders of the bank.
A pioneering attempt at providing a fairly detailed outline of Islamic
banking was made in Urdu by Siddiqi in l968. (The English version was not
published until l983.) His Islamic banking model was based on mudaraba and
shirka (partnership or musharaka as it is now usually called). His model was
essentially one based on a two-tier mudaraba financier-entrepreneur
relationship, but he took pains to describe the mechanics of such
transactions in considerable detail with numerous hypothetical and
arithmetic examples. He classified the operations of an Islamic bank into
three categories: services based on fees, commissions or other fixed charges;
financing on the basis of mudaraba and partnership; and services provided
free of charge. His thesis was that such interest-free banks could be a viable
alternative to interest-based conventional banks.
The issue of loans for consumption clearly presents a problem, as there is no
profit to be shared. Siddiqi addressed this problem, but he managed only to
scratch the surface. While recognizing the need for such interest-free loans
(qard hasan), especially for meeting basic needs, he seemed to think it was
the duty of the community and the State (through its baitul mal or treasury)
to cater to those needs; the Islamic bank's primary objective, like that of any other business unit, is to earn profit. He therefore tended to downplay the
role of Islamic banks in providing consumption loans, but he suggested
limited overdraft facilities without interest. He even considered a portion of
the fund being set aside for consumption loans, repayment being guaranteed
by the State. He also suggested that consumers buying durables on credit
would issue 'certificates of sale' which could be encashed by the seller at the bank for a fee. It was then the seller not the buyer who would be liable as far as the bank was concerned. However, the principles of murabaha and bai'
muajjal were not invoked.
Strangely, Siddiqi favoured keeping the number of shareholders to the
minimum, without advancing any strong reasons. This is contrary to the
general consensus which now seems to have emerged with reference to
Islamic banks operating on a joint stock company basis, a consensus which
incidentally is also in line with the Islamic value attached to a broad equity base as against heavy concentration of equity and wealth. Ironically, Siddiqi thought that interest-free banking could operate successfully 'only in a
country where interest is legally prohibited and any transaction based upon
interest is declared a punishable offense' (l983b:l3). He also thought it
important to have Islamic laws enforced before interest-free banking could
operate well. This view has not gained acceptance, as demonstrated by the
many Islamic banks which operate profitably in 'hostile' environments, as
noted earlier.
Chapra's model of Islamic banking (Chapra l982), like Siddiqi's, was based on
the mudaraba principle. His main concern, however, centered on the role of
artificial purchasing power through credit creation. He even suggested that
'seigniorage' resulting from it should be transferred to the public
exchequer, for the sake of equity and justice. Al-Jarhi (l983) went so far as to favor the imposition of a l00 per cent reserve requirement on commercial
banks. Chapra was also much concerned about the concentration of
economic power private banks might enjoy in a system based on equity
financing. He therefore preferred medium-sized banks which are neither so
large as to wield excessive power nor so small as to be uneconomical.
Chapra's scheme also contained proposals for loss-compensating reserves
and loss-absorbing insurance facilities. He also spoke of non-bank financial
institutions, which specialize in bringing financiers and entrepreneurs
together and act as investment trusts.
Mohsin (l982) has presented a detailed and elaborate framework of Islamic
banking in a modern setting. His model incorporates the characteristics of
commercial, merchant, and development banks, blending them in novel
fashion. It adds various non-banking services such as trust business,
factoring, real estate, and consultancy, as though interest-free banks could
not survive by banking business alone. Many of the activities listed
certainly go beyond the realm of commercial banking and are of so
sophisticated and specialized a nature that they may be thought irrelevant to
most Muslim countries at their present stage of development. Mohsin's model
clearly was designed to fit into a capitalist environment; indeed he explicitly stated that riba-free banks could coexist with interest-based banks.
The point that there is more to Islamic banking than mere abolition of interest was driven home strongly by Chapra (l985). He envisaged Islamic banks
whose nature, outlook and operations could be distinctly different from those of conventional banks. Besides the outlawing of riba, he considered it
essential that Islamic banks should, since they handle public funds, serve
the public interest rather than individual or group interests. In other words,
they should play a social-welfare-oriented rather than a profit-maximizing
role. He conceived of Islamic banks as a cross-breed of commercial and
merchant banks, investment trusts and investment-management institutions
that would offer a wide spectrum of services to their customers. Unlike
conventional banks which depend heavily on the 'crutches of collateral and
of non-participation in risk' (p. l55), Islamic banks would have to rely heavily on project evaluation, especially for equity-oriented financing. Thanks to the profit-and-loss sharing nature of the operations, bank-customer
relations would be much closer and more cordial than is possible under
conventional banking. Finally, the problems of liquidity shortage or surplus
would have to be handled differently in Islamic banking, since the ban on
interest rules out resort to the money market and the central bank. Chapra
suggested alternatives such as reciprocal accommodation among banks
without interest payments and creation of a common fund at the central
bank into which surpluses would flow and from which shortages could be
met without any interest charges.
The literature also discusses the question of central banking in an Islamic
framework. The general opinion seems to be that the basic functions of a
modern central bank are relevant also for an Islamic monetary system,
although the mechanisms may have to be different. Thus, for example, the
bank rate instrument cannot be used as it entails interest. Uzair (l982) has
suggested adjustments in profit-sharing ratios as a substitute for bank rate
manipulations by the central bank. Thus, credit can be tightened by
reducing the share accruing to the businessmen and eased by increasing it.
Siddiqi (l982) has suggested that variations in the so-called 'refinance ratio' (which refers to the central bank refinancing of a part of the interest-free
loans provided by the commercial banks) would influence the quantum of
short-term credit extended. Siddiqi has also proposed a prescribed 'lending
ratio' (i.e., the proportion of demand deposits that commercial banks are
obliged to lend out as interest-free loans) that can be adjusted by the central bank according to changing circumstances. In this context, reference may
also be made to a proposal by Uzair (l982) that the central bank should
acquire an equity stake in commercial banking by holding, say, 25 per cent
of the capital stock of the commercial banks. The rationale behind this
proposal was that it would give the central bank access to a permanent
source of income so that it could effectively act as lender of last resort.
The discussion of central banking in an Islamic context is somewhat scanty,
presumably because Islamic central banking is viewed as too far-fetched an
idea, except in Iran and Pakistan.
It emerges from all this that Islamic banking has three distinguishing
features: (a) it is interest-free, (b) it is multi-purpose and not purely commercial, and (c) it is strongly equity-oriented. The literature contains hardly any serious criticism of the interest-free character of the operation, since
this is taken for granted, although concerns have been expressed about the
lack of adequate interest-free instruments. There is a near-consensus that
Islamic banks can function well without interest. A recent International
Monetary Fund study by Iqbal and Mirakhor (l987) has found Islamic
banking to be a viable proposition that can result in efficient resource
allocation. The study suggests that banks in an Islamic system face fewer solvency and liquidity risks than their conventional counterparts.
The multi-purpose and extra-commercial nature of the Islamic banking
operation does not seem to pose intractable problems. The abolition of
interest makes it imperative for Islamic banks to look for other instruments,
which renders operations outside the periphery of commercial banking
unavoidable. Such operations may yield economies of scope. But it is
undeniable that the multipurpose character of Islamic banking poses serious
practical problems, especially in relation to the skills needed to handle such
diverse and complex transactions (Iqbal and Mirakhor l987).
The stress on equity-oriented transactions in Islamic banking, especially the
mudaraba mode, has been criticized. It has been argued that the replacement
of pre-determined interest by uncertain profits is not enough to render a
transaction Islamic, since profit can be just as exploitative as interest is, if it is 'excessive' (Naqvi l98l). Naqvi has also pointed out that there is nothing sacrosanct about the institution of mudaraba in Islam. Naqvi maintains that mudaraba is not based on the Qur'an or the Hadith but was a custom of the
pre-Islamic Arabs. Historically, mudaraba, he contends, enabled the aged,
women, and children with capital to engage in trade through merchants for
a share in the profit, all losses being borne by the owners of capital, and
therefore it cannot claim any sanctity. The fact remains that the Prophet
raised no objection to mudaraba, so that it was at least not considered un-Islamic.
The distribution of profit in mudaraba transactions presents practical
difficulties, especially where there are multiple providers of capital, but
these difficulties are not regarded as insurmountable. The Report of
Pakistan's Council of Islamic Ideology (CII l983) has suggested that the
respective capital contributions of parties can be converted to a common
denominator by multiplying the amounts provided with the number of days
during which each component, such as the firm's own equity capital, its
current cash surplus and suppliers' credit was actually deployed in the
business, i.e., on a daily product basis. As for deposits, profits (net of
administrative expenses, taxes, and appropriation for reserves) would be
divided between the shareholders of the bank and the holders of deposits,
again on a daily product basis.
Recent years have brought an increasing flow of empirical studies of Islamic
banking. The earliest systematic empirical work was undertaken by Khan
(l983). His observations covered Islamic banks operating in Sudan, United
Arab Emirates, Kuwait, Bahrain, Jordan, and Egypt. Khan's study showed that
these banks had little difficulty in devising practices in conformity with
Shariah. He identified two types of investment accounts: one where the
depositor authorized the banks to invest the money in any project and the
other where the depositor had a say in the choice of project to be financed.
On the asset side, the banks under investigation had been resorting to
mudaraba, musharaka and murabaha modes. Khan's study reported profit
rates ranging from 9 to 20 per cent which were competitive with
conventional banks in the corresponding areas. The rates of return to
depositors varied between 8 and l5 per cent, which were quite comparable
with the rates of return offered by conventional banks.
Khan's study revealed that Islamic banks had a preference for trade finance
and real estate investments. The study also revealed a strong preference for
quick returns, which is understandable in view of the fact that these newly
established institutions were anxious to report positive results even in the
early years of operation. Nienhaus (1988) suggests that the relative
profitability of Islamic banks, especially in the Middle East in recent years,
was to a large extent due to the property (real estate) boom. He has cited cases
of heavy losses which came with the crash of the property sector.
The IMF study referred to earlier by Iqbal and Mirakhor (l987) also contains
extremely interesting empirical observations, although these are confined to
the experience of Iran and Pakistan, both of which have attempted to
islamize the entire banking system on a comprehensive basis.
Iran switched to Islamic banking in August l983 with a three-year transition
period. The Iranian system allows banks to accept current and savings
deposits without having to pay any return, but it permits the banks to offer
incentives such as variable prizes or bonuses in cash or kind on these
deposits. Term deposits (both short-term and long-term) earn a rate of return
based on the bank's profits and on the deposit maturity. No empirical
evidence is as yet available on the interesting question as to whether
interest or a profit-share provides the more effective incentive to depositors
for the mobilization of private saving. Where Islamic and conventional
banks exist side by side, central bank control of bank interest rates is liable to be circumvented by shifts of funds to the Islamic banks.
Iqbal and Mirakhor have noted that the conversion to Islamic modes has
been much slower on the asset than on the deposit side. It appears that the
Islamic banking system in Iran was able to use less than half of its resources
for credit to the private sector, mostly in the form of short-term facilities,
i.e., commercial and trade transactions. The slower pace of conversion on the
asset side was attributed by the authors to the inadequate supply of personnel trained in long-term financing. The authors, however, found no evidence to
show that the effectiveness of monetary policy in Iran, broadly speaking,
was altered by the conversion.
The Pakistani experience differs from the Iranian one in that Pakistan had
opted for a gradual islamization process which began in l979. In the first
phase, which ended on l January l985, domestic banks operated both interest-
free and interest-based 'windows'. In the second phase of the transformation
process, the banking system was geared to operate all transactions on the
basis of no interest, the only exceptions being foreign currency deposits,
foreign loans and government debts. The Pakistani model took care to ensure
that the new modes of financing did not upset the basic functioning and
structure of the banking system. This and the gradual pace of transition,
according to the authors, made it easier for the Pakistani banks to adapt to
the new system. The rate of return on profit-and-loss sharing (PLS) deposits
appears not only to have been in general higher than the interest rate
before islamization but also to have varied between banks, the differential
indicating the degree of competition in the banking industry. The authors
noted that the PLS system and the new modes of financing had accorded
considerable flexibility to banks and their clients. Once again the study
concluded that the effectiveness of monetary policy in Pakistan was not
impaired by the changeover.
The IMF study, however, expressed considerable uneasiness about the
concentration of bank assets on short-term trade credits rather than on
long-term financing. This the authors found undesirable, not only because it
is inconsistent with the intentions of the new system, but also because the
heavy concentration on a few assets might increase risks and destabilize the
asset portfolios. The study also drew attention to the difficulty experienced in both Iran and Pakistan in financing budget deficits under a non-interest
system and underscored the urgent need to devise suitable interest-free
instruments. Iran has, however, decreed that government borrowing on
the basis of a fixed rate of return from the nationalized banking system
would not amount to interest and would hence be permissible. The official
rationalization is that, since all banks are nationalized, interest rates and
payments among banks will cancel out in the consolidated accounts. (This, of
course, abstracts from the banks' business with non-bank customers.)
There are also some small case studies of Islamic banks operating in
Bangladesh (Huq l986), Egypt (Mohammad l986), Malaysia (Halim l988b),
Pakistan (Khan l986), and Sudan (Salama l988b). These studies reveal
interesting similarities and differences. The current accounts in all cases are operated on the principles of al-wadiah. Savings deposits, too, are accepted
on the basis of al-wadiah, but 'gifts' to depositors are given entirely at the
discretion of the Islamic banks on the minimum balance, so that the
depositors also share in profits. Investment deposits are invariably based on
the mudaraba principle, but there are considerable variations. Thus, for
example, the Islamic Bank of Bangladesh has been offering PLS Deposit
Accounts, PLS Special Notice Deposit Accounts, and PLS Term Deposit
Accounts, while Bank Islam Malaysia has been operating two kinds of
investment deposits, one for the general public and the other for
institutional clients.
The studies also show that the profit-sharing ratios and the modes of
payment vary from place to place and from time to time. Thus, for example,
profits are provisionally declared on a monthly basis in Malaysia, on a
quarterly basis in Egypt, on a half-yearly basis in Bangladesh and Pakistan,
and on an annual basis in Sudan.
A striking common feature of all these banks is that even their investment
deposits are mostly short-term, reflecting the depositors' preference for
assets in as liquid a form as possible. Even in Malaysia, where investment
deposits have accounted for a much larger proportion of the total, the bulk of
them were made for a period of less than two years. By contrast, in Sudan
most of the deposits have consisted of current and savings deposits,
apparently because of the ceiling imposed by the Sudanese monetary
authorities on investment deposits which in turn was influenced by limited
investment opportunities in the domestic economy.
There are also interesting variations in the pattern of resource utilization by the Islamic banks. For example, musharaka has been far more important
than murabaha as an investment mode in Sudan, while the reverse has been
the case in Malaysia. On the average, however, murabaha, bai'muajjal and
ijara, rather than musharaka represent the most commonly used modes of
financing. The case studies also show that the structure of the clientele has
been skewed in favor of the more affluent segment of society, no doubt
because the banks are located mainly in metropolitan centres with small
branch networks.
The two main problems identified by the case studies are the absence of
suitable non-interest-based financial instruments for money and capital
market transactions and the high rate of borrower delinquency. The former
problem has been partially redressed by Islamic banks resorting to mutual
inter-bank arrangements and central bank cooperation, as mentioned
earlier. The Bank Islam Malaysia, for instance, has been placing its excess
liquidity with the central bank which usually exercises its discretionary
powers to give some returns. The delinquency problem appears to be real
and serious. Murabaha payments have often been held up because late
payments cannot be penalized, in contrast to the interest system in which
delayed payments would automatically mean increased interest payments. To
overcome this problem, the Pakistani banks have resorted to what is called
'mark-down' which is the opposite of 'mark-up' (i.e., the profit margin in the
cost-plus approach of murabaha transactions). 'Mark-down' amounts to
giving rebates as an incentive for early payments. But the legitimacy of this
'mark-down' practice is questionable on Shariah grounds, since it is time-
based and therefore smacks of interest.
In the Southeast Asian context, two recent studies on the Bank Islam Malaysia
by Man (l988) and the Philippine Amanah Bank by Mastura (l988) deserve
special mention. The Malaysian experience in Islamic banking has been
encouraging. Man's study shows that the average return to depositors has
been quite competitive with that offered by conventional banks. By the end
of l986, after three years of operation, the bank had a network of fourteen
branches. However, 90 per cent of its deposits had maturities of two years or
less, and non-Muslim depositors accounted for only 2 per cent of the total.
Man is particularly critical of the fact that the mudaraba and musharaka
modes of operation, which are considered most meaningful by Islamic
scholars, accounted for a very small proportion of the total investment portfolio, while bai'muajjal and ijara formed the bulk of the total.
It is evident from Mastura's analysis that the Philippine Amanah Bank is,
strictly speaking, not an Islamic bank, as interest-based operations continue
to coexist with Islamic modes of financing. Thus, the PAB has been operating
both interest and Islamic 'windows' for deposits. Mastura's study has
produced evidence to show that the PAB has been concentrating on
murabaha transactions, paying hardly any attention to the mudaraba and
musharaka means of financing. The PAB has also been adopting unorthodox
approaches in dealing with excess liquidity by making use of interest-
bearing treasury bills. Nonetheless, the PAB has also been invoking some
Islamic modes in several major investment activities. Mastura has made
special references to the qirad principle adopted by the PAB in the Kilu-sang
Kabuhayan at Kaunlaran (KKK) movement launched under Marcos and to
the ijara financing for the acquisition of farm implements and supplies in
the Quedon food production program undertaken by the present regime.
So far no reference has been made to Indonesia, the largest Muslim country
in the world, with Muslims accounting for 90 per cent of a population of
some 165 million. The explanation is that a substantial proportion, especially
in Java, are arguably nominal Muslims. Indonesians by and large subscribe
to the Pancasila ideology which is essentially secular in character. The
present regime seems to associate Islamic banking with Islamic
fundamentalism to which the regime is not at all sympathetic. Besides, the
intellectual tradition in Indonesia in modern times has not been conducive to
the idea of interest-free banking. There were several well respected
Indonesian intellectuals including Hatta (the former Vice President) who
had argued that riba prohibited in Islam was not the same as interest
charged or offered by modern commercial banks, although Islamic jurists in
Indonesia hold the opposite view. The Muslim public seems somewhat
indifferent to all this. This, however, does not mean that there are no
interest-free financial institutions operating in Indonesia. One form of
traditional interest-free borrowing is the still widely prevalent form of
informal rural credit known as ijon (green) because the loan is secured on
the standing crop as described by Partadireja (1974). Another is the arisan
system practiced among consumers and small craftsmen and traders. In this
system, each member contributes regularly a certain sum and obtains
interest-free loans from the pool by drawing lots. The chances of an Islamic
bank being established in Indonesia seem at present remote (cf. Rahardjo
1988).
Finally, in the most recent contribution to the growing Islamic banking
literature, Nien-haus (l988) concludes that Islamic banking is viable at the
microeconomic level but dismisses the proponents' ideological claims for
superiority of Islamic banking as 'unfounded'. Nienhaus points out that
there are some failure stories. Examples cited include the Kuwait Finance
House which had its fingers burned by investing heavily in the Kuwaiti real
estate and construction sector in l984, and the Islamic Bank International of
Denmark which suffered heavy losses in l985 and l986 to the tune of more
than 30 per cent of its paid-up capital. But then, as Nienhaus himself has
noted, the quoted troubles of individual banks had specific causes and it
would be inappropriate to draw general conclusions from particular cases.
Nienhaus notes that the high growth rates of the initial years have been
falling off, but he rejects the thesis that the Islamic banks have reached
their 'limits of growth' after filling a market gap. The falling growth rates
might well be due to the bigger base values, and the growth performance of
Islamic banks has been relatively better in most cases than that of
conventional banks in recent years.
According to Nienhaus, the market shares of many Islamic banks have
increased over time, notwithstanding the deceleration in the growth of
deposits. The only exception was the Faisal Islamic Bank of Sudan (FIBS)
whose market share had shrunk from l5 per cent in l982 to 7 per cent in l986,
but Nien-haus claims that the market shares lost by FIBS were won not by
conventional banks but by newer Islamic banks in Sudan.
Short-term trade financing has clearly been dominant in most Islamic banks
regardless of size. This is contrary to the expectation that the Islamic banks would be active mainly in the field of corporate financing on a participation basis. Nien-haus attributes this not only to insufficient supply by the banks but also to weak demand by entrepreneurs who may prefer fixed interest cost
to sharing their profits with the banks.
The preceding discussion makes it clear that Islamic banking is not a
negligible or merely temporary phenomenon. Islamic banks are here to stay
and there are signs that they will continue to grow and expand. Even if one
does not subscribe to the Islamic injunction against the institution of
interest, one may find in Islamic banking some innovative ideas which could
add more variety to the existing financial network.
One of the main selling points of Islamic banking, at least in theory, is that, unlike conventional banking, it is concerned about the viability of the
project and the profitability of the operation but not the size of the collateral. Good projects which might be turned down by conventional banks for
lack of collateral would be financed by Islamic banks on a profit-sharing
basis. It is especially in this sense that Islamic banks can play a catalytic role in stimulating economic development. In many developing countries, of
course, development banks are supposed to perform this function. Islamic
banks are expected to be more enterprising than their conventional
counterparts. In practice, however, Islamic banks have been concentrating
on short-term trade finance which is the least risky.
Part of the explanation is that long-term financing requires expertise which
is not always available. Another reason is that there are no back-up
institutional structures such as secondary capital markets for Islamic financial instruments. It is possible also that the tendency to concentrate on
short-term financing reflects the early years of operation: it is easier to
administer, less risky, and the returns are quicker. The banks may learn to
pay more attention to equity financing as they grow older.
It is sometimes suggested that Islamic banks are rather complacent. They
tend to behave as though they had a captive market in the Muslim masses
who will come to them on religious grounds. This complacency seems more
pronounced in countries with only one Islamic bank. Many Muslims find it
more convenient to deal with conventional banks and have no qualms about
shifting their deposits between Islamic banks and conventional ones
depending on which bank offers a better return. This might suggest a case
for more Islamic banks in those countries as it would force the banks to be
more innovative and competitive. Another solution would be to allow the
conventional banks to undertake equity financing and/or to operate Islamic
'counters' or 'windows', subject to strict compliance with the Shariah rules. It is perhaps not too wild a proposition to suggest that there is a need for specialized Islamic financial institutions such as mudaraba banks, murabaha
banks and musharaka banks which would compete with one another to
provide the best possible services.
al-wadiah = safe keeping
bai'muajjal = deferred-payment sale
bai'salam = pre-paid purchase
baitul mal = treasury
fiqh = jurisprudence
Hadith = Prophet's commentary on Qur'an
hajj = pilgrimage
halal = lawful
haram = unlawful
ijara = leasing
iman = faith
mithl = like
mudaraba = profit-sharing
mudarib = entrepreneur-borrower
muqarada = mudaraba
murabaha = cost-plus or mark-up
musharaka = equity participation
qard hasan = benevolent loan (interest free)
qirad = mudaraba
rabbul-mal = owner of capital
riba = interest
Shariah = Islamic law
shirka = musharaka
Islamic Financial Institutions (outside Pakistan and Iran)
Australia Islamic Investment Company, Melbourne.
Bahamas Dar al Mal al Islami, Nassau Islamic Investment Company Ltd, Nassau,
Masraf Faisal Islamic Bank & Trust, Bahamas Ltd.
Bahrain Albaraka Islamic Investment Bank, Manama, Bahrain Islamic Bank, Manama,
Bahrain Islamic Investment Company, Manama, Islamic Investment Company of the Gulf,
Masraf Faisal al Islami, Bahrain.
Bangladesh Islamic Bank of Bangladesh Ltd, Dhaka.
Denmark Islamic Bank International of Denmark, Copenhagen.
Egypt Albaraka Nile Valley Company, Cairo, Arab Investment Bank (Islamic Banking
Operations), Cairo., Bank Misr (Islamic Branches), Cairo, Faisal Islamic Bank of Egypt, Cairo,
General Investment Company, Cairo, Islamic International Bank for Investment and Development,
Cairo, Islamic Investment and Development Company, Cairo, Nasir Social Bank, Cairo.
Guinea Islamic Investment Company of Guinea, Conakry, Masraf Faisal al Islami of Guinea, Conakry.
India Baitun Nasr Urban Cooperative Society, Bombay.
Jordan Islamic Investment House Company Ltd Amman, Jordan Finance House, Amman,
Jordan Islamic Bank for Finance and Investment, Amman.
Kibris (Turkish Cyprus) Faisal Islamic Bank of Kibris, Lefkosa.
Kuwait Al Tukhaim International Exchange Company, Safat., Kuwait Finance House, Safat.
Liberia African Arabian Islamic Bank, Monrovia.
Liechtenstein Arinco Arab Investment Company, Vaduz, Islamic Banking System Finance S.A. Vaduz.
Luxembourg Islamic Finance House Universal Holding S.A.
Malaysia Bank Islam Malaysia Berhad, Kuala Lumpur, Pilgrims Management and Fund Board, Kuala Lumpur.
Mauritania Albaraka Islamic Bank, Mauritania.
Niger Faisal Islamic Bank of Niger, Niamy.
Philippines Philippine Amanah Bank, Zamboanga.
Qatar Islamic Exchange and Investment Company, Doha, Qatar Islamic Bank.
Saudi Arabia Albaraka Investment and Development Company, Jeddah, Islamic Development
Bank, Jeddah.
Senegal Faisal Islamic Bank of Senegal, Dakar, Islamic Investment Company of Senegal, Dakar.
South Africa JAAME Ltd, Durban.
Sudan Bank al Baraka al Sudani, Khartoum, Faisal Islamic Bank of Sudan, Khartoum,
Islamic Bank of Western Sudan, Khartoum, Islamic Cooperative Development Bank, Khartoum,
Islamic Investment Company of Sudan, Khartoum, Sudan Islamic Bank, Khartoum,
Tadamun Islamic Bank, Khartoum, Jersey The Islamic Investment Company, St Helier,
Masraf Faisal al Islami, St Helier.
Switzerland Dar al Mal al Islami, Geneva., Islamic Investment Company Ltd, Geneva,
Shariah Investment Services, PIG, Geneva.
Thailand Arabian Thai Investment Company Ltd, Bangkok.
Tunisia Bank al Tamwil al Saudi al Tunisi.
Turkey Albaraka Turkish Finance House, Istanbul, Faisal Finance Institution, Istanbul.
U.A.E. Dubai Islamic Bank, Dubai, Islamic Investment Company Ltd, Sharjah.
U.K. Albaraka International Ltd, London, Albaraka Investment Co. Ltd, London, Al Rajhi Company
for Islamic Investment Ltd, London, Islamic Finance House Public Ltd Co., London.
The list includes Islamic banks as well as Islamic investment companies but it
does not include Islamic insurance or takaful companies.
Source: Siddiqi (l988)
Abdallah, A., 1987. 'Islamic banking', Journal of Islamic Banking and
Finance, January-March, 4(1): 31-56.
Abdeen, A.M. and Shook, D.N., 1984. The Saudi Financial System, J. Wiley and
Sons, Chichester.
Abdel-Magib, M.F., 1981. 'Theory of Islamic banks: accounting implications',
International Journal of Accounting, Fall: 78-102.
Aftab, M., 1986. 'Pakistan moves to Islamic banking', The Banker, June: 57-60.
Ahmad, Sheikh Mahmud, l952. Economics of Islam, Lahore.
____, n.d. 'Interest and Unemployment', Islamic Studies, Islamabad, VIII (l):
9-46.
Al-Arabi, Mohammad Abdullah, l966. 'Contemporary banking transactions
and Islam's views thereon', Islamic Review, London, May l966: l0-l6.
Al-Jarhi, Ma'bid Ali, l983. 'A monetary and financial tructure for an interest-
free economy, institutions, mechanism and policy', in Ziauddin, Ahmad et al.
(eds.), Money and Banking in Islam, International Centre for Research in
Islamic Economics, Jeddah, and Institute of Policy Studies, Islamabad.
Ali, M. (ed.) l982. Islamic Banks and Strategies of Economic Cooperation, New
Century Publishers, London.
____ (ed.) 1984. Papers on Islamic Banking, New Century Publishers, London.
Ariff, M. l982. 'Monetary policy in an interest-free Islamic economy - nature
and scope' in M. Ariff, (ed.), Monetary and Fiscal Economics of Islam,
International Centre for Research in Islamic Economics, Jeddah.
____ 1988. Islamic Banking in South-east Asia, Institute of Southeast Asian
Studies, Singapore.
Bruce, N.C., 1986. 'Islamic banking moves east', Euromoney, July: 142-5.
Chapra, M. Umer, l982. 'Money and banking in an Islamic economy' in M
Ariff (ed.), above.
____ l985. Toward a Just Monetary System, The Islamic Foundation, Leicester.
Choudhury, Masul Alam, l986. Contributions to Islamic Economic Theory: A
Study in Social Economics, St Martin Press, New York.
Council of Islamic Ideology (CII), Pakistan, l983. 'Elimination of interest from
the economy', in Ziauddin, Ahmed et al. (eds.).
El-Asker, A.A.F., 1987. The Islamic Business Enterprise, Croom Helm, London.
El-Din, A.K., 1986. 'Ten years of Islamic banking', Journal of Islamic Banking
and Finance, July-September, 3(3):49-66.
Halim, Abdul, l986. 'Sources and uses of funds: a study of Bank Islam Malaysia
Berhad,' paper presented to the Seminar on Developing a System of Islamic
Financial Instruments, organized by the Ministry of Finance Malaysia and
the Islamic Development Bank, Kuala Lumpur.
Hjarpe, Jan, l986. 'Mudaraba banking and taka-ful insurance: the question of
"Islamic Banks", their significance and possible impact', in Jan Selmer, and
Loong Hoe Tan, Economic Relations between Scandinavia and ASEAN: Issues
on Trade, Investment, Technology Transfer and Business Culture, University
of Stockholm and Institute of South-east Asian Studies, Singapore.
Homoud, S.H., 1985. Islamic Banking, Arabian Information, London.
Huq, Azizul, l986. 'Utilization of financial investments: a case study of
Bangladesh', paper submitted to the Seminar on Developing a System
of Islamic Financial Instruments, organized by the Ministry of Finance Malaysia
and the Islamic Development Bank, Kuala Lumpur.
Iqbal, Zubair and Mirakhor, Abbas, l987. Islamic Banking, International
Monetary Fund Occasional Paper 49, Washington D.C.
Irshad, S.A., l964. Interest-Free Banking, Orient Press of Pakistan, Karachi.
Kahf, Monzer, l982a. 'Saving and investment functions in a two-sector
Islamic economy', in M. Ariff (ed.) , above.
____ l982b. 'Fiscal and monetary policies in an Islamic economy', in M. Ariff
(ed.),above.
Karsten, I., 1982. 'Islam and financial intermediation', IMF Staff Papers,
March, 29(1):108-42.
Khan, Abdul Jabbar, l986. 'Non-interest banking in Pakistan: a case study',
paper presented to the Seminar on Developing a System of Islamic Financial
Instruments, organized by the Ministry of Finance Malaysia and the Islamic
Development Bank, Kuala Lumpur.
Khan, M. Fahim, l983. 'Islamic banking as practised now in the world' in
Ziauddin, Ahmad et al. (eds.).
Khan, M. S.,1986.'Islamic interest-free banking', I M F Staff Papers, March,
33(1):1-27.
____, 1987 'Principles of monetary policy in an Islamic framework', paper
presented to the International Institute of Islamic Economics, Islamabad,
Pakistan, July.
____, and Mirakhor, A., 1986. 'The frame-work and practice of Islamic
banking', Finance and Development, September.
____ and ____, 1987. Theoretical Studies in Islamic Banking and Finance (Book
Distribution Centre, Houston.
____ and ____ forth-coming (1988). 'The financial system and monetary policy
in an Islamic economy', Journal of Research in Islamic Economics.
Khan, Muhammad Akram, l968. 'Theory of employment in Islam', Islamic
Literature, Karachi, XIV (4): 5-l6.
____ n.d. 'International monetary crisis, causes and cure', The Criterion,
Karachi, 6 (2): 5-l9.
Khan, W.M., l985. Towards an Interest-Free Islamic Economic System, The
Islamic Foundation, Leicester.
Man, Zakariya, l988. 'Islamic banking: the Malaysian experience', in M. Ariff
(ed.), above.
Mannan, M.A., l970. Islamic Economics, Lahore.
Mastura, Michael O., l988. 'Islamic banking: the Philippine experience', in M.
Ariff (ed.), above.
Mirakhor, Abbas, 1986. 'Some theoretical aspects of an Islamic financial
system', paper presented at a Conference on Islamic Banking sponsored by
the Central Bank of the Islamic Republic of Iran, Tehran, 11-14 June.
Mohsin, M., l982. 'Profile of riba-free banking', in M. Ariff (ed.), above.
Naqvi, S.N.H., l98l. Ethics and Economics: An Islamic Synthesis, The Islamic
Foundation, Leicester.
____, l982. 'Interest rate and intertemporal allocative efficiency in an
Islamic economy', in M. Ariff (ed.), above.
Naughton, S.A.J. and Tahir, M.A., 1988. 'Islamic banking and financial development',
Journal of Islamic Banking and Finance, 5 (2).
Nienhaus, V., l983. 'Profitability of Islamic PLS banks competing with
interest banks: problems and prospects', Journal of Research in Islamic
Economics, l(l):37-47.
____, l986. 'Islamic economics, finance and banking - theory and practice',
Journal of Islamic Banking and Finance, 3(2):36-54.
____, l988. 'The performance of Islamic banks - trends and cases', paper
presented to the Conference on Islamic Law and Finance, convened in the
University of London, 8 April.
Partadireja, Ace, 1974. 'Rural credit: the Ijon system', Bulletin of Indonesian
Economic Studies, 10 (3): 54-71.
Qureshi, Anwar Iqbal, l946. Islam and the Theory of Interest, Lahore.
Rahardjo, Dawam, 1988. 'Islamic banking in Indonesia?' in M. Ariff (ed.),
above.
Rahman, Fazalur, n.d. 'Riba and interest', Islamic Studies, Karachi, 3(l):l-43.
Ready, R.K., l98l. 'The march toward self-determination', paper presented at
the First Advanced Course on Islamic Banks, International Institute of Islamic
Banking and Economics, Cairo, 28 August - l7 September.
Rosa, D.A., 1986. 'Islamic financial policies and domestic resource mobilisation',
Savings and Development, 2:143-53.
Salama, Abidin Ahmad, l986. 'Utilisation of financial instruments: a case
study of Faisal Islamic Bank (Sudan)', paper submitted to the Seminar on
Developing a System of Islamic Financial Instruments, organized by the
Ministry of Finance Malaysia and the Islamic Development Bank, Kuala
Lumpur.
Scharf, T.W., 1983. Arab and Islamic Banks, OECD, Paris.
Siddiqi, M.N., l982. 'Islamic Approaches to Money, Banking and Monetary
Policy: A Review', in M. Ariff (ed.), above.
____, l983a. Banking Without Interest, The Islamic Foundation, Leicester.
____, 1983b. Issues in Islamic Banking, Islamic Foundation, Leicester.
____, 1985. Partnership and Profit-Sharing in Islamic Law, Islamic
Foundation, Leicester.
____, l988. 'Islamic banking: theory and practice', in M. Ariff (ed.), above.
Su'ud, M. Abu, n.d. 'The economic order within the general conception of the
Islamic way of life', Islamic Review, London, 55 (2): 24-26 and (3): ll-l4.
Udovitch, Abraham L., l970. Partnership and Profit in Medieval Islam,
Princeton University Press, Princeton, N.J.
Uzair, Mohammad, l955. An Outline of `Interestless Banking', Raihan Publications, Karachi.
____, l982. 'Central banking operations in an interest-free banking system',
in M. Ariff (ed.), above.
Zaidi, N.A., l987. 'Profit rates policy for PLS depositors', Journal of Islamic
Banking and Finance, 4 (4): 35-46.
1 Surah al-Rum (Chapter 30), verse 39; Surah al-Nisa (Chapter 39), verse l6l;
Surah al-Imran (Chapter 3), verses l30-2; Surah al-Baqarah (Chapter 2),
verses 275-8l. See Yusuf Ali's Translation of the Qur'an.
2 Hadith compiled by Muslims (Kitab al-Musaqat).
3 This refers to a Hadith compiled by Muslims (Kitab al-Musaqat).
4 Bank Islam Malaysia Berhad has been offering a 70:30 profit-sharing ratio
in favour of depositors (Man l988).
5 In l984 the Islamic Bank of Bangladesh offered rates of return ranging
from 4.95 per cent to l4.l3 per cent. The Faisal Islamic Bank of Egypt, Cairo,
gave a 9 per cent rate of return on deposits in the same year (Afkar Inquiry,
December l985).
6 According to Sharia, profits arising from a mudaraba arrangement can be
divided in any proportion between the two contracting parties as agreed
upon at the time of the contract, but losses, if any, will fall on the financier
only.
7 Some Muslim countries have recently introduced what are called 'Muqarada
Bonds', the proceeds of which are to be used for income-yielding public
utility projects such as the construction of bridges and roads. The bond
holders will have a share in the collection of tolls and other receipts.
8 Qirad, sometimes also called muqarada, refers to a financial arrangement
whereby the financier gets a share in the output, as in the case of Muqarada
Bonds (see footnote 7). In the literature, the terms qirad and mudaraba are
often used interchangeably.
9 The market shares of the Islamic banks are close to 20 per cent in Egypt,
Kuwait and Sudan and roughly l0 per cent in Jordan and Qatar. By contrast,
in Turkey, Islamic banks account for less than 1 per cent of the market (see
Nienhaus 1988).
This document can be acquired from a sub-directory coombspapers via anonymous
FTP on the node COOMBS.ANU.EDU.AU
|